Our local supermarket was open yesterday, a Sunday. This is a very rare event and I suspect it means it'll be closed today, during what the Spanish call un puente, a 'bridge' - the extra day taken off when a public holiday falls on a Thursday or a Tuesday. In other words, the intervening Friday or Monday, respectively. I should stress I'm talking about my barrio of Poio only. Across the bridge in Pontevedra city, the situation could be very different.
Regular readers will know why I loved this paragraph in a local paper yesterday: We can't deny it; roundabouts are a weak point for the majority of drivers. In fact, 2 out of 3 of us still don't know who has priority on them, making for unnecessary danger.
If you really want to know the details of the 5 different foundational laws on education in Spain since 1970 - and if you can at least read Spanish - see this useful article in yesterday's Voz de Galicia.
The President of the Galician government - the Xunta - has had a salary increase of 7.5%, taking it to €72,000 a year. Which must have gone down well with all those whose income hasn't increased in several years. Not to mention those on a salary below the legal minimum. And the very many unemployed.
Talking of salaries . . . One of the oddities of Spanish life is that they're normally quoted on a monthly basis. And, even if you're sure they're pre-tax, you never know whether the amount is received 12 times a year or 13, 14 or even 15. Comparing annual gross salaries is, thus, rather difficult. Another oddity is that Spanish measurements of blood pressure come as, for example, 14/10 and not, say, 138/97. And then there's the university entrance marks, which are given out of 14. It used to be out of 10 but someone clearly thought this wasn't unusual or confusing enough.
It's all going one way in the EU, isn't it?, as events do their best to prove the accuracy of my long-standing prediction that the institution will eventually collapse under the weight of its internal incongruities. A day or so ago, we had the German Finance Minister instructing Greece to shape up or ship out of the eurozone; and now we have yesterday's negative referendum result in Italy. Which places yet another huge question mark over the whole EU shooting match. Here's Don Quijones on the latter development. As he puts it: All bets on Italy’s political, economic, and financial stability are, once again, off. And by extension, the stability – what remains of it – of the Eurozone. If it wasn't so serious, I'd do a bit of gloating.
Anyway, there's an interesting article at the end of this post on why the EU is - and always has been - wrong for Europe.
Finally . . . Today's cartoon:-
Europe’s divisions
have driven our success: Matt Ridley, The Times
The Italian referendum
and close-shave Austrian election are symptoms of a continent that
may be teetering on the brink of political disintegration. It’s
just possible that an empire may be collapsing before our eyes, as
the Habsburg and Ottoman empires did before it, in or around the same
neighbourhood.
With the rise of
nationalist parties in Italy, Austria, Hungary, Poland, the
Netherlands, France, Germany and Britain, the possibility that the
Brussels union has fomented, rather than suppressed, nationalism can
no longer be dismissed. The Habsburg empire, which also tried to make
a whole out of linguistically and culturally diverse parts, and ended
in a war sparked by Serbian nationalism, is an unhappy precedent. The
European Union may be encouraging precisely what it was founded to
avert.
True, it is an empire
without a hereditary emperor, founded on high ideals of peace and
prosperity. But at least initially, Napoleon’s empire was also
founded on the principle of replacing old regimes with a more
meritocratic and modern system.
Against this
background, it is worth recalling that the leading theory among
economic historians for why Europe after 1400 became the wealthiest
and most innovative continent is political fragmentation. Precisely
because it was not unified, Europe became a laboratory for different
ways of governing, enabling the discovery of regimes that allowed
free markets and invention to flourish, first in northern Italy and
some parts of Germany, then the low countries, then Britain. By
contrast, China’s unity under one ruler prevented such
experimentation.
It is generally assumed
that it was Charles, Baron Montesquieu who first articulated this
theory, in De L’Esprit Des Lois (1748). In contrast to the great
empires of Asia, he remarked, Europe’s “many medium-sized states”
had incubated “a genius for liberty, which makes it very difficult
to subjugate each part and to put it under a foreign force other than
by laws and by what is useful to its commerce”.
I think David Hume got
there first, however. In his 1742 essay Of the Rise and Progress of
the Arts and Sciences, he mused on why China’s “considerable
stock of politeness and science” had not ripened, and blamed the
fact that it was one vast empire, so “the authority of any teacher,
such as Confucius, was propagated easily from one corner of the
empire to the other. None had courage to resist the torrent of
popular opinion.” By contrast, Europe is the continent “most
broken by seas, rivers, and mountains” and so “the divisions into
small states are favourable to learning, by stopping the progress of
authority as well as that of power”.
Whoever first thought
of it, the idea has gained almost universal agreement among
historians that a disunited Europe, while frequently wracked by war,
was also prone to innovation and liberty — thanks to the ability of
innovators and skilled craftsmen to cross borders in search of more
congenial regimes.
In The European Miracle
(1981), Eric Jones claimed that “Against the economies of scale
that large empires could offer, the decentralisation of Europe’s
states-system offered flexibility and a family of experiments in
government decision-making”. Since then, the historians Nathan
Rosenberg, Paul Kennedy, Jared Diamond and Joel Mokyr have all echoed
the same point in books. Mokyr, in a 2007 essay, pointed out that
Paracelsus, Comenius, Descartes, Hobbes and Bayle “survived through
strategic moves across national boundaries”. He could have added
Gutenberg, Columbus, Papin, Voltaire and more to his list.
In the early 18th
century an ambitious chemist and would-be alchemist named Johann
Friedrich Böttger showed up at the court of Augustus the Strong,
elector of Saxony, claiming to have discovered how to make gold. He
was promptly imprisoned in a castle by the prince lest he move on and
offer his technology to a rival ruler — thus illustrating Hume’s
point. Böttger did not of course know how to make gold, but he did
work out how to make fine porcelain to rival China’s. The castle
was called Meissen.
During the 18th
century, Britain experimented with a light tax burden compared with
the Dutch Republic. Dutch businessmen moved to Britain in large
numbers, bringing with them their technologies and ideas. In China,
they could not have escaped uniform taxes, at whatever level they
were. The differential between the Dutch Republic and England
narrowed, suggesting that the Dutch authorities were trying to hold
taxation back to slow the exodus.
In other words, free
movement of genius was crucial to Europe’s success. Perhaps equally
important was the free movement of skilled artisans. Jones noted that
“the Murano glassmakers spread their arts across Europe despite
severe penalties threatened by the Venetian authorities”. But there
was a crucial difference from what the European Union means by free
movement of people today. These people were moving not because the
rules were the same everywhere, but because they were different. The
European Commission’s obsession with harmonisation prevents the
very pattern of experimentation that encourages innovation.
Whereas the states
system positively encouraged governments to be moderate in political,
religious and fiscal terms or lose their talent, the commission
detests jurisdictional competition, in taxes and regulations. The
larger the empire, the less brake there is on governmental excess.
So, an ambitious
genetic engineer, who has devised a way in the laboratory to suppress
agricultural pests and eradicate disease-carrying mosquitoes, by
releasing genetically modified males that cause infertility among
their offspring, has nowhere to go within the EU to find a regime
that will license his experiment in the wild. Like Columbus leaving
Genoa for Spain, he goes to the United States instead, eventually
selling his British-born business to an American company that can
afford to build a GM-mosquito factory in Brazil to combat the zika
and dengue viruses. This is a real example: the company is called
Oxitec.
In effect, the European
continent is saying to innovative thinkers the opposite of what it
said for centuries. Where once it signalled that they could exile
themselves and take their ideas with them to sow in more fertile
ground, now it is saying: it does not matter how far you move within
Europe, we want to be sure you can never escape the same rules. With
east-west and north-south differences within the EU building, that
feels increasingly like a tension that must break in the years ahead.
No comments:
Post a Comment